Occupational segregation
Occupational segregation is the distribution of workers across and within occupations, based upon demographic characteristics, most often gender.[1] Occupational segregation levels differ on a basis of perfect segregation and integration. Perfect segregation occurs where any given occupation employs only one group. Perfect integration, on the other hand, occurs where each group holds the same proportion of positions in an occupation as it holds in the labor force.[2]
Many scholars, such as Biblarz et al., argue that occupational segregation is most likely caused by gender-based discrimination[3] that often occurs in patterns, either horizontally (across occupations) or vertically (within the hierarchy of occupations). As a workplace phenomenon, it is linked to the gender pay gap and reduced labor participation.[4][5]
Types
Horizontal
Horizontal segregation refers to differences in the number of people of each gender present across occupations.[6] Horizontal segregation is likely to be increased by post-industrial restructuring of the economy (post-industrial society), in which the expansion of service industries has called for many women to enter the workforce. The millions of housewives who entered the economy during post-industrial restructuring primarily entered into service sector jobs where they could work part-time and having flexible hours. While these options are often appealing to mothers, who are often responsible for the care work of their children and their homes,[6] they are also unfortunately most available in lower-paying and lower status occupations. The idea that nurses and teachers are often pictured as women whereas doctors and lawyers are often assumed to be men are examples of how highly engrained horizontal segregation is in our society.
Vertical
The term vertical segregation describes men's domination of the highest status jobs in both traditionally male and traditionally female occupations.[6] Colloquially, the existence of vertical segregation is referred to as allowing men to ride in a "glass escalator" through which women must watch as men surpass them on the way to the top positions.[7] Generally, the more occupational segregation present in a country, the less vertical segregation there is because women have a better chance of obtaining the highest positions in a given occupation as their share of employment in that particular occupation increases.[8]
Vertical segregation can be somewhat difficult to measure across occupations because it refers to hierarchies within individual occupations. For example, the category of Education Professionals, (a category in the Australian Standard Classification of Occupations, Second Edition), is broken down into "School Teachers," "University and Vocational Education Teachers," and "Miscellaneous Education Professionals." These categories are then further broken down into subcategories. While these categories aptly describe the divisions within education, they are not comparable to the hierarchical categories within other occupations, and thus make comparisons of levels of vertical segregation quite difficult.[8]
Maintenance mechanisms
Self-selection
Some women self-select out of higher status positions, choosing instead to have more time to spend at home and with their families. According to Sarah Damaske, this choice is often made because high status positions do not allow time for the heavy domestic workload that many women expect to take on due to the gendered division of labor in the home.[6] Working-class women, in particular, also sometimes self-select out of more time-intensive or higher -status positions in order to maintain the traditional gender hierarchy and household accord.[9]
Educational disparities
Human capital explanations are those that argue that an individual's and a group's occupational and economic success can be at least partially attributed to accumulated abilities developed through formal and informal education and experiences.[10] Human capital explanations for occupational segregation, then, posit that a difference in educational levels of men and women is responsible for persistent occupational segregation. Because of their alleged fewer educational merits, their lower salary is justified.[11] Contrary to this theory, however, over past 40 years, women's educational attainment has outpaced men's. One area of education that might play a substantial role in occupational segregation, however, is the dearth of women in science and mathematics.[12] STEM fields tend to be pipelines to higher paying jobs. Therefore, the lack of women in higher paying jobs might be partially because they do not pursue science and mathematics in school. This can be seen in areas such as finance, which is very mathematics heavy and is also a very popular field for those who eventually rise to high status positions in the private sector. This choice, like others, is often a personal preference or made because of the cultural idea that women are not as good as men at mathematics.[12]
Work experience disparities
Human capital explanations also posit that men tend to rise to higher positions than women because of a disparity in work experience between the genders. Indeed, the gap between men and women's tenure rises with age, and female college graduates are more likely than males to interrupt their careers to raise children.[12] Such choices may also be attributed to the gendered division of labor which holds women primarily responsible for domestic duties.
Preferences
Human capital explanations posit additionally that men are more likely than women to preference their work life over their family life. However, the General Social Survey found that men were only slightly less likely than women to value short hours, and that preferences for particular job characteristics depended mostly on age, education, race, and other characteristics rather than on gender.[12] In addition, other research has shown that men and women likely hold endogenous job preferences, meaning that their preferences are due to the jobs they hold and those they have held in the past rather than related inherently to gender. After taking into consideration men and women's jobs, there is no difference in their job preferences. Men and women engaged in similar types of work have similar levels of commitment to work and display other similar preferences.[12]
Job search strategies
According to sociologists Hanson and Pratt, men and women employ different strategies in their job searches that play a role in occupational segregation. These differing strategies are influenced by power relations in the household, the gendered nature of social life, and women's domestic responsibilities. The last factor, in particular, leads women to prioritize the geographical proximity of paid employment when searching for a job. In addition, most people have been found to find their jobs through informal contacts. The gendered nature of social life leads women to have networks with smaller geographical reach than men. Thus, the location of women in female-dominated occupations which are lower-status and lower pay is the result of "severe day-to-day time constraints" rather than a conscious and long-term choice made that would be able to maximize pay and prestige.[13]
Gender
Gender pay gap
Women in female-dominated jobs pay two penalties: the average wage of their jobs is lower than that in comparable male-dominated jobs, and they earn less relative to men in the same jobs. Since 1980, occupational segregation is the single largest factor of the gender pay gap, accounting for over half of the wage gap.[14] In addition, women's wages are negatively affected by the percentage of females in a job, but men's wages are essentially unaffected.[15] The crowding hypothesis postulates that occupational segregation lowers all women's earnings as a result of women's exclusion from primarily male occupations and segregation into a number of predominantly female-dominated occupations.[5] Given that feminine skills are traditionally rewarded less both in salary and prestige, the crowding of women into certain occupations makes these occupations valued less in both pay and prestige.
Crowding is found to be alleviated through macro-changes in occupational segregation. Teaching, for example, at least in recent generations, is traditionally a female- dominated profession. However, when positions open up for women in business and other high-earning occupations, school boards must raise the salaries of potential teachers to attract candidates. This is an example of how even women in traditionally female-dominated professions still benefit salary-wise from the gendered integration of the market.[5]
Gendered division of labor
The gendered division of labor helps to explain the hierarchy of power across gender identity, class, race, ethnicity, and sexual orientation.[16] Socialist feminists contribute to this ideology through a Marxist frame of alienated labor and the means of production. Heidi Hartmann emphasized the gendered division of labor as patriarchal control over women's labor. Wally Saccombe suggested the mode of production should become a unity of production and reproduction, in which women's reproductive abilities are viewed as a valuable source of labor or income.[17] The "wages for housework" movement in the late 1970s showcased the importance of gender inequality in the workplace. Socialist feminists critiqued the exploitation of women's household and reproductive labor, since it was not viewed as a commodity that deserved payment in the market economy.[18] Women often experience working a "double day" or "second shift" when they go to a wage-earning job and then come home to take care of children and the home.[19]
Measurement
Occupational segregation is measured using Duncan's D (or the index of dissimilarity), which serves as a measure of dissimilarity between two distributions. D has to be calculated first:
- Identify N different occupations.
- Calculate the percentage of men (or other ascribed category) who work in each of the occupations and the percentage of women who work in each occupation. Give men and women a variable name (m1 could = men, w1 could = women).
- Duncan's D is calculated using this formula: D=½εi|m1-w1|
- It is important to note that Duncan's D uses percentages. So in a given occupation, the number of men (or women) in that occupation should be divided by the total number of men (or women) in all of the occupations. For example: You may have 10 men who are nurses out of 600 total men. The value for the occupation of male nurses should be 10/600, or .0166.
In the United States
Over the last century in the United States, there has been a surprising stability of segregation-index scores, which measure the level of occupational segregation of the labor market.[6] There were declines in occupational segregation in the 1970s and 1980s, as technologies that made the care work of the home quicker and easier allowed more women time to enter the workforce.[20] However, occupational segregation remains a fixed element of the United States workforce today. As recently as 1996, it has been found that gender occupational segregation over the past three generations has not decreased. In one study, grown women working in the 1980s were likely to have faced the same occupational segregation faced by their mothers working in the 1960s and their grandmothers working in the 1940s.[3]
Solutions
Gender egalitarian cultural principles, or changes in traditional gender norms, are one possible solution to occupational segregation in that they reduce discrimination, affect women's self-evaluations, and support structural changes. Horizontal segregation, however, is more resistant to change from simply modern egalitarian pressures.[6] Changes in norms may reinforce the impact of occupational integration in that once people see women in traditionally male-dominated occupations, their expectations about women in the labor market might be changed.[5]
Some scholars, such as Haveman and Beresford, therefore argue that any policies aimed at reducing occupational inequality must focus on culture changes.[12] According to Haveman and Beresford, people in the United States have historically tended to reject policies that only support one group (unless that group is them). Therefore, effective policies for limiting occupational segregation must aim to provide benefits across groups. Therefore, policies that aim at capping work hours for salaried workers or mandate on-site employer sponsored childcare might be most effective.[12]
In addition, the more occupational integration that occurs, the more women are in the positions to make powerful decisions affecting occupational segregation. If the overall market becomes less segregated, those who make personnel decisions in traditionally female-dominated occupations will have to make jobs, even higher status jobs, more attractive to women to retain them. School boards, for example, will have to appoint more women to department head positions and other positions of authority in order to retain women workers, whereas those jobs might previously have gone to men.[5]
On the basis of sexual orientation
In addition to gender, sexual orientation can also be a significant basis for occupational segregation: there is a disproportionately high number of gay and lesbian workers in certain occupations. Research shows that gay men are more likely to be in female-majority occupations than are heterosexual men, and lesbians are more represented in male-majority occupations than are heterosexual women, but even after accounting for this tendency, common to both gay men and lesbians is a propensity to concentrate in occupations that provide task independence or require social perceptiveness, or both.[21]
See also
- Achievement gap in the United States
- Division of labour
- Gender equality
- Glass ceiling
- Mommy track
- Occupational inequality
- Occupational sexism
- Online segregation
- Shared earning/shared parenting marriage
- Social stratification
References
- Bergmann 1981.
- Weeden 2007.
- Biblarz, Bengtson & Bucur 1996.
- "Fact Sheet: Occupational Segregation in the United States". Equitable Growth.
- Cotter et al. 1997.
- Charles 2003.
- Snyder, Karrie Ann and Adam Isaiah Green. 2008. "'Revisiting the Glass Escalator: The Case of Gender Segregation in a Female Dominated Occupation." Social Problems 55(2): 271-299.
- Watts 2005.
- Damaske 2004.
- Mincer 1891.
- Loutfi, Martha Fetherolf (2001). Women, Gender, and Work: What is Equality and How Do We Get There?. International Labour Organization. ISBN 92-2-111386-8. Retrieved 21 October 2019.
- Haveman & Beresford 2012.
- Hanson & Pratt 1991.
- "Fact Sheet: Occupational Segregation in the United States". Equitable Growth.
- Cohen & Bianchi 1999.
- Mills, Mary Beth (2003). "Gender and Inequality in the Global Labor Force". Annual Review of Anthropology. 32: 41–62. doi:10.1146/annurev.anthro.32.061002.093107.
- Burris, Val. "The Dialectic of Women's Oppression: Notes of the Relation Between Capitalism and Patriarchy". Berkeley Journal of Sociology. 27: 51–74.
- Bergeron, Suzanne. "Formal, Informal, and Care Economies". Oxford Handbook of Feminist Theory.
- Bromley, Victoria (2012). Feminisms Matter. University of Toronto Press.
- Cohen 2004.
- Tilcsik, Anteby & Knight 2015.
Bibliography
- Bergmann, B.R. (1981). "The Economic Risks of Being a Housewife". The American Economic Review (71): 81–6.CS1 maint: ref=harv (link)
- Biblarz, T. J.; Bengtson, V. L.; Bucur, A. (1996). "Social mobility across three generations". Journal of Marriage and the Family. 58 (1): 188–200. doi:10.2307/353387. JSTOR 353387.CS1 maint: ref=harv (link)
- Chafetz, J.S. (1988). "The Gender Division of Labor and the Reproduction of Female Disadvantage: Toward an Integrated Theory". Journal of Family Issues. 9: 108–131. doi:10.1177/019251388009001006.CS1 maint: ref=harv (link)
- Charles, M. (2003). "Deciphering Sex Segregation: Vertical and Horizontal Inequalities in Ten National Labor Markets". Acta Sociologica. 46 (4): 267–287. doi:10.1177/0001699303464001.CS1 maint: ref=harv (link)
- Cohen, P. (2004). "The Gender Division of Labor: 'Keeping House' and Occupational Segregation in the United States". Gender and Society. 18 (2): 239–52. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.536.7134. doi:10.1177/0891243203262037.CS1 maint: ref=harv (link)
- Cohen, P.N.; Bianchi, S.M. (1999). "Marriage, children, and women's employment: What do we know?". Monthly Labor Review (122): 22–31.CS1 maint: ref=harv (link)
- Cotter, D.A.; DeFiore, J.; Hermsen, J.M.; Kowalewski, B.M.; Vanneman, R. (1997). "All women benefit: The macro-level effect of occupational integration on gender earnings equality". American Sociological Review. 62 (5): 714–34. doi:10.2307/2657356. JSTOR 2657356.
- Damaske, S. (2004). "A 'Major Career Woman'? How Women Develop Early Expectations About Work". Gender and Society (25): 409–430.CS1 maint: ref=harv (link)
- Hanson, S.; Pratt, G. (1991). "Job Search and the Occupational Segregation of Women". Annals of the American Association of Geographers. 81 (2): 229–253. doi:10.1111/j.1467-8306.1991.tb01688.x.CS1 maint: ref=harv (link)
- Haveman, H.A.; Beresford, L.S. (2012). "If you're so smart, why aren't you the boss? Explaining the persistent vertical gender gap in management" (PDF). The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science. 639: 114–30. doi:10.1177/0002716211418443.CS1 maint: ref=harv (link)
- Mincer, J. (1891). "Human Capital and Economic Growth". NBER Working Paper (802).CS1 maint: ref=harv (link)
- Tilcsik, A.; Anteby, M.; Knight, C. (2015). "Concealable Stigma and Occupational Segregation: Toward a Theory of Gay and Lesbian Occupations" (PDF). Administrative Science Quarterly. 60 (3): 446–481. doi:10.1177/0001839215576401.CS1 maint: ref=harv (link)
- Watts, M.J. (2005). "On the Conceptualisation and Measurement of Horizontal and Vertical Occupational Gender Segregation". European Sociological Review. 21 (5): 481–488. doi:10.1093/esr/jci034.CS1 maint: ref=harv (link)
- Weeden, K. (2007). Ritzer, George (ed.). Occupational Segregation. Blackwell Encyclopedia of Sociology. Blackwell Publishing.CS1 maint: ref=harv (link)
- Online: "Blackwell Reference Online". 31 March 2008.