Inflation targeting
Inflation targeting is a monetary policy where a central bank follows an explicit target for the inflation rate for the medium-term and announces this inflation target to the public. The assumption is that the best that monetary policy can do to support long-term growth of the economy is to maintain price stability, and price stability is achieved by controlling inflation. The central bank uses interest rates, its main short-term monetary instrument.[1][2][3]
An inflation-targeting central bank will raise or lower interest rates based on above-target or below-target inflation, respectively. The conventional wisdom is that raising interest rates usually cools the economy to rein in inflation; lowering interest rates usually accelerates the economy, thereby boosting inflation. The first three countries to implement fully-fledged inflation targeting were New Zealand, Canada and the United Kingdom in the early 1990s, although Germany had adopted many elements of inflation targeting earlier.[4][5]
History
Early proposals of monetary systems targeting the price level or the inflation rate, rather than the exchange rate, followed the general crisis of the gold standard after World War I. Irving Fisher proposed a "compensated dollar" system in which the gold content in paper money would vary with the price of goods in terms of gold, so that the price level in terms of paper money would stay fixed. Fisher's proposal was a first attempt to target prices while retaining the automatic functioning of the gold standard. In his Tract on Monetary Reform (1923), John Maynard Keynes advocated what we would now call an inflation targeting scheme. In the context of sudden inflations and deflations in the international economy right after World War I, Keynes recommended a policy of exchange rate flexibility, appreciating the currency as a response to international inflation and depreciating it when there are international deflationary forces, so that internal prices remained more or less stable. Interest in inflation targeting waned during the Bretton Woods era (1944–1971), as they were inconsistent with the exchange rate pegs that prevailed during three decades after World War II.
New Zealand, Canada, United Kingdom
Inflation targeting was pioneered in New Zealand in 1990.[6] Canada was the second country to formally adopt inflation targeting in February 1991.[4][5]
The United Kingdom adopted inflation targeting in October 1992 after exiting the European Exchange Rate Mechanism.[4][7] The Bank of England's Monetary Policy Committee was given sole responsibility in 1998 for setting interest rates to meet the Government's Retail Prices Index (RPI) inflation target of 2.5%.[8] The target changed to 2% in December 2003 when the Consumer Price Index (CPI) replaced the Retail Prices Index as the UK Treasury's inflation index.[9] If inflation overshoots or undershoots the target by more than 1%, the Governor of the Bank of England is required to write a letter to the Chancellor of the Exchequer explaining why, and how he will remedy the situation.[10][11][12] The success of inflation targeting in the United Kingdom has been attributed to the Bank's focus on transparency.[7] The Bank of England has been a leader in producing innovative ways of communicating information to the public, especially through its Inflation Report, which have been emulated by many other central banks.[4]
Inflation targeting then spread to other advanced economies in the 1990s and began to spread to emerging markets beginning in the 2000s.
European Central Bank
Although the ECB does not consider itself to be an inflation-targeting central bank,[13] after the inception of the euro in January 1999, the objective of the European Central Bank (ECB) has been to maintain price stability within the Eurozone.[14] The Governing Council of the ECB in October 1998[15] defined price stability as inflation of under 2%, "a year-on-year increase in the Harmonised Index of Consumer Prices (HICP) for the euro area of below 2%" and added that price stability "was to be maintained over the medium term".[16] The Governing Council confirmed this definition in May 2003 following a thorough evaluation of the ECB's monetary policy strategy. On that occasion, the Governing Council clarified that "in the pursuit of price stability, it aims to maintain inflation rates below, but close to, 2% over the medium term".[15] Since then, the numerical target of 2% has become common for major developed economies, including the United States (since January 2012) and Japan (since January 2013).[17]
Emerging markets
In 2000, Frederic S. Mishkin concluded that "although inflation targeting is not a panacea and may not be appropriate for many emerging market countries, it can be a highly useful monetary policy strategy in a number of them".[18]
Chile
In Chile, a 20% inflation rate pushed the Central Bank of Chile to announce at the end of 1990 an inflation objective for the annual inflation rate for the year ending in December 1991.[18] However, Chile was not regarded as a fully-fledged inflation targeter until 1999.[5]
Czech Republic
The Czech National Bank (CNB) is an example of an inflation targeting central bank in a small open economy with a recent history of economic transition and real convergence to its Western European peers. Since 2010 the CNB uses 2 percent with a +/- 1pp range around it as the inflation target.[19] The CNB places a lot of emphasis on transparency and communication; indeed, a recent study of more than 100 central banks found the CNB to be among the four most transparent ones.[20]
In 2012, inflation was expected to fall well below the target, leading the CNB to gradually reduce the level of its basic monetary policy instrument, the 2-week repo rate, until the zero lower bound (actually 0.05 percent) was reached in late 2012. In light of the threat of a further fall in inflation and possibly even of a protracted period of deflation, on 7 November 2013 the CNB declared an immediate commitment to weaken the exchange rate to the level of 27 Czech korunas per 1 euro (day-on-day weakening by about 5 percent) and to keep the exchange rate from getting stronger than this value until at least the end of 2014 (later on this was changed to the second half of 2016). The CNB thus decided to use the exchange rate as a supplementary tool to make sure that inflation returns to the 2 percent target level. Such a use of the exchange rate as tool within the regime of inflation targeting should not be confused with a fixed exchange-rate system or with a currency war.[21][22][23]
United States
In a historic shift on 25 January 2012, U.S. Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke set a 2% target inflation rate, bringing the Fed in line with many of the world's other major central banks.[24] Until then, the Fed's policy committee, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), did not have an explicit inflation target but regularly announced a desired target range for inflation (usually between 1.7% and 2%) measured by the personal consumption expenditures price index.
Prior to adoption of the target, some people argued that an inflation target would give the Fed too little flexibility to stabilise growth and/or employment in the event of an external economic shock. Another criticism was that an explicit target might turn central bankers into what Mervyn King, former Governor of the Bank of England, had in 1997 colorfully termed "inflation nutters"[25]—that is, central bankers who concentrate on the inflation target to the detriment of stable growth, employment, and/or exchange rates. King went on to help design the Bank's inflation targeting policy,[26] and asserts that the buffoonery has not actually happened, as did Chairman of the U.S. Federal Reserve Ben Bernanke, who stated in 2003 that all inflation targeting at the time was of a flexible variety, in theory and practice.[27]
Former Chairman Alan Greenspan, as well as other former FOMC members such as Alan Blinder, typically agreed with the benefits of inflation targeting, but were reluctant to accept the loss of freedom involved; Bernanke, however, was a well-known advocate.[28]
Theoretical questions
New classical macroeconomics and rational expectations hypothesis can explain how and why inflation targeting works. Expectations of firms (or the subjective probability distribution of outcomes) will be around the prediction of the theory itself (the objective probability distribution of those outcomes) for the same information set.[29] So, rational agents expect the most probable outcome to emerge. However, there is limited success at specifying the relevant model, and the full and perfect knowledge of a given macroeconomic system can be regarded as a comfortable presumption at best. Knowledge of the relevant model is not feasible, even if high-level econometrical techniques were accessible or adequate identification of the relevant explanatory variables were performed. So, estimation bias depends on the quantity and quality of information to which the modeller has access. In other words, estimations are asymptotically unbiased with respect to the exploited information.
Meanwhile, consistency can be interpreted similarly. On the basis of asymptotical unbiasedness, a moderated version of the rational expectations hypothesis can be suggested in which familiarity with the theoretical parameters is not a requirement for the relevant model. An agent with access to sufficiently vast, quality information and high-level methodological skills could specify its own quasi-relevant model describing a specific macroeconomic system. By increasing the amount of information processed, this agent could further reduce its bias. If this agent were also focal, such as a central bank, then other agents would likely accept the proposed model and adjust their expectations accordingly. In this way, individual expectations become unbiased as much as possible, albeit against a background of considerable passivity. According to some researches, this is the theoretical background of the functionality of inflation targeting regimes.[30]
Debate
There is some empirical evidence that inflation targeting does what its advocates claim, that is, making the outcomes, if not the process, of monetary policy more transparent.[31][32]
Benefits
Inflation targeting allows monetary policy to "focus on domestic considerations and to respond to shocks to the domestic economy", which is not possible under a fixed exchange-rate system. Also, investor uncertainty is reduced and therefore investors may more easily factor in likely interest rate changes into their investment decisions. Inflation expectations that are better anchored "allow monetary authorities to cut policy interest rates countercyclically".[33]
Transparency is another key benefit of inflation targeting. Central banks in developed countries that have successfully implemented inflation targeting tend to "maintain regular channels of communication with the public". For example, the Bank of England pioneered the "Inflation Report" in 1993, which outlines the bank's "views about the past and future performance of inflation and monetary policy".[34] Although it was not an inflation-targeting country until January 2012, up until then, the United States' "Statement on Longer-Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy" enumerated the benefits of clear communication—it "facilitates well-informed decisionmaking by households and businesses, reduces economic and financial uncertainty, increases the effectiveness of monetary policy, and enhances transparency and accountability, which are essential in a democratic society".[35]
An explicit numerical inflation target increases a central bank's accountability, and thus it is less likely that the central bank falls prey to the time-inconsistency trap. This accountability is especially significant because even countries with weak institutions can build public support for an independent central bank. Institutional commitment can also insulate the bank from political pressure to undertake an overly expansionary monetary policy.[18]
An econometric analysis found that although inflation targeting results in higher economic growth, it does not necessarily guarantee stability based on their study of 36 emerging economies from 1979 to 2009.[36]
Shortcomings
Supporters of a nominal income target criticize the propensity of inflation targeting to neglect output shocks by focusing solely on the price level. Adherents of market monetarism, led by Scott Sumner, argue that in the United States, the Federal Reserve's mandate is to stabilize both output and the price level, and that consequently a nominal income target would better suit the Fed's mandate.[37] Australian economist John Quiggin, who also endorses nominal income targeting, stated that it "would maintain or enhance the transparency associated with a system based on stated targets, while restoring the balance missing from a monetary policy based solely on the goal of price stability".[38] Quiggin blamed the late-2000s recession on inflation targeting in an economic environment in which low inflation is a "drag on growth". In reality, however, it is not true that inflation targeters focus solely on the rate of inflation and disregard economic growth: instead they tend to conduct "flexible inflation targeting" where the central bank strives to keep inflation near the target except time periods when such an effort would imply too much output volatility.[39][40]
Quiggin also criticized former Fed Chair Alan Greenspan and former European Central Bank President Jean-Claude Trichet for "ignor[ing] or even applaud[ing] the unsustainable bubbles in speculative real estate that produced the crisis, and to react[ing] too slowly as the evidence emerged".[38]
In a 2012 op-ed, University of Nottingham economist Mohammed Farhaan Iqbal suggested that inflation targeting "evidently passed away in September 2008", referencing the 2007–2012 global financial crisis. Frankel suggested "that central banks that had been relying on [inflation targeting] had not paid enough attention to asset-price bubbles", and also criticized inflation targeting for "inappropriate responses to supply shocks and terms-of-trade shocks". In turn, Iqbal suggested that nominal income targeting or product-price targeting would succeed inflation targeting as the dominant monetary policy regime.[41] The debate continues and many observers expect that inflation targeting will continue to be the dominant monetary policy regime, perhaps after certain modifications.[42]
Empirically, it is not so obvious that inflation targeters have better inflation control. Some economists argue that better institutions increase a country's chances of successfully targeting inflation.[43] As regards the impact of the recent financial crisis, John Williams, a high-ranking Federal Reserve official, concludes that "when gauged by the behavior of inflation since the crisis, inflation targeting delivered on its promise".[44]
Choosing a positive, zero, or negative inflation target
Choosing a positive inflation target has at least two drawbacks.
- Over time, the compounded effect of small annual price increases will significantly reduce a currency's purchasing power. (For example, successfully hitting a target of +2% each year for 40 years would cause the price of a $100 basket of goods to rise to $220.80.) This drawback would be minimized or reversed by choosing a zero inflation target or a negative target.
- Vendors must expend resources more frequently to reprice their goods and services. This drawback would be minimized by choosing a zero inflation target.
However, policymakers feel the drawbacks are outweighed by the fact that a positive inflation target reduces the chance of an economy falling into a period of deflation.
Some economists argue that fear of deflation is unfounded, citing studies that show inflation is more likely than deflation to cause an economic contraction.[45][46] Andrew Atkeson and Patrick J. Kehoe wrote,
- According to standard economic theory, deflation is the necessary consequence of optimal monetary policy. In 1969, Milton Friedman argued that under the optimal policy, the nominal interest rate should be zero and the price level should fall steadily at the real rate of interest. Since then, Friedman’s argument has been confirmed in a formal setting. (See, for example, V. V. Chari, Lawrence Christiano, and Patrick Kehoe 1996 and Harold Cole and Narayana Kocherlakota 1998.)[47]
Effectively, Friedman was arguing for a negative (moderately deflationary) inflation target.
Countries
There were 27 countries regarded by the Bank of England's Centre for Central Banking Studies as fully fledged inflation targeters at the beginning of 2012.[5] Other lists count 26 or 28 countries as of 2010.[48][49] Since then, the United States and Japan have also adopted inflation targets although the Federal Reserve, like the European Central Bank,[13] does not consider itself to be an inflation-targeting central bank.
Country | Central bank | Year adopted inflation targeting | Notes |
---|---|---|---|
New Zealand | Reserve Bank of New Zealand | 12/1989[5] | The pioneer; see Section 8: Reserve Bank of New Zealand Act of 1989. |
Canada | Bank of Canada | 02/1991[5] | |
United Kingdom | Bank of England | 10/1992[5] | First in Europe, although Germany had adopted many elements of inflation targeting earlier.[4] |
Sweden | Sveriges Riksbank | 01/1993[5] | The inflation target regime was announced in January 1993 and applied as of 1995.[5] The Riksbank had practiced price-level targeting since abandonment of the gold standard in 1931. |
Australia | Reserve Bank of Australia | 06/1993[5][50] | |
Israel | Bank of Israel | 06/1997[5] | Informally since 1992. Fully fledged inflation targeting from June 1997.[5][51] |
Czech Republic | Czech National Bank | 12/1997[5][52] | First in Central and Eastern Europe. |
Poland | National Bank of Poland | 1998[5] | |
Brazil | Brazilian Central Bank | 06/1999[5] | |
Chile | Central Bank of Chile | 09/1999[5] | At the end of 1990, a 20% inflation rate pushed the Central Bank of Chile to announce an inflation objective for the annual inflation rate for the year ending in December 1991.[18] |
Colombia | Banco de la República | 10/1999[5] | |
South Africa | South African Reserve Bank | 02/2000[5] | |
Thailand | Bank of Thailand | 05/2000[5] | |
Mexico | Bank of Mexico | 2001[5] | Some sources say 1999.[53] |
Norway | Norges Bank | 03/2001[5][54][55] | |
Iceland | Central Bank of Iceland | 03/2001[56] | |
Peru | Central Reserve Bank of Peru | 01/2002[5] | |
Philippines | Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas | 01/2002[5][57] | |
Guatemala | Bank of Guatemala | 01/2005[5] | |
Indonesia | Bank Indonesia | 07/2005[5] | |
Romania | National Bank of Romania | 08/2005[5] | |
Armenia, Republic of | Central Bank of Armenia | 01/2006[5] | |
Turkey | Türkiye Cumhuriyet Merkez Bankası | 01/2006[5] | |
Ghana | Bank of Ghana | 05/2007[5] | Informally in 2002, formally from May 2007.[5] |
Georgia | National Bank of Georgia | 01/2009[58] | |
Serbia, Republic of | National Bank of Serbia | 01/2009[5] | |
United States | Federal Reserve | 01/2012[59] | |
Japan | Bank of Japan | 01/2013[60] | |
Russian Federation | Central Bank of Russia | 01/2014[61] | |
Republic of Kazakhstan | National Bank of Republic of Kazakhstan | 08/2015[62] | |
Ukraine | National Bank of Ukraine | 08/2015[63] | Official document about implementation of inflation targeting in Ukraine[64] |
India | Reserve Bank of India | 08/2016[65] | Decision taken after India had ~10% inflation rate for around 5 years. |
Argentina | Central Bank of Argentina | 09/2016[66] | Until September 2018, when the Central Bank changed its monetary policy to crawling peg.
|
In addition, South Korea (Bank of Korea) and Iceland (Central Bank of Iceland) and others.[5]
Variations
Contrast to the usual inflation rate targeting, Laurence Ball proposed targeting on long-run inflation, targeting which takes the exchange rate into account and monetary conditions index targeting.[67] In his proposal, the monetary conditions index is a weighted average of the interest rate and exchange rate. It will be easy to put many other things into this monetary conditions index.
In the "constrained discretion" framework, inflation targeting combines two contradicting monetary policies—a rule-based approach and a discretionary approach—as a precise numerical target is given for inflation in the medium term and a response to economic shocks in the short term. Some inflation targeters associate this with more economic stability.[2][68]
References
- Coy, Peter (7 November 2005). "What's The Fuss Over Inflation Targeting?". BusinessWeek (The New Fed). Archived from the original on 28 July 2011.
- Jahan, Sarwat. "Inflation Targeting: Holding the Line". International Monetary Funds, Finance & Development. Retrieved 28 December 2014.
-
Fisher, Irving (1922). . In Chisholm, Hugh (ed.). Encyclopædia Britannica (12th ed.). London & New York. - "Inflation Targeting Has Been A Successful Monetary Policy Strategy". NBER. Retrieved 31 October 2016.
- "State of the art of inflation targeting" (PDF). Bank of England – Centre for Central Banking Studies. 2012: 17, 18–44. Archived from the original (PDF) on 11 August 2017. Cite journal requires
|journal=
(help) - Andrew G. Haldane (1995). Targeting Inflation: A Conference of Central Banks on the Use of Inflation Targets Organised by the Bank of England, 9-10 March 1995. London: Bank of England. ISBN 9781857300734.
- "Targeting Inflation: The United Kingdom in Retrospect" (PDF). IMF. Retrieved 31 October 2016.
- "Key Monetary Policy Dates Since 1990". Bank of England. Archived from the original on 29 June 2007. Retrieved 20 September 2007.
- "Remit of the Monetary Policy Committee of the Bank of England and the New Inflation Target" (PDF). HM Treasury. 10 December 2003. Archived (PDF) from the original on 26 September 2007. Retrieved 20 September 2007.
- "Monetary Policy Framework". Bank of England. Retrieved 31 October 2016.
- "CCBS Lecture Series - Inflation Targeting: The British Experience". Bank of England. January 1999. Retrieved 31 October 2016.
- "Inflation targeting is 25 years old, but has it worked?". BBC. 11 March 2015. Retrieved 31 October 2016; "Why do we target 2pc inflation? (And does it matter if we keep missing it?)". The Telegraph. 16 June 2015. Retrieved 31 October 2016.
- Governor Laurence H. Meyer (17 July 2001). "Inflation Targets and Inflation Targeting". The Federal Reserve Board. Retrieved 1 December 2016.
- wikisource consolidation
- THE EUROPEAN CENTRAL BANK HISTORY, ROLE AND FUNCTIONS BY HANSPETER K. SCHELLER SECOND REVISED EDITION 2006, ISBN 92-899-0022-9 (print) ISBN 92-899-0027-X (online) page 81 at the pdf online version
- "Powers and responsibilities of the European Central Bank". European Central Bank. Archived from the original on 16 December 2008. Retrieved 10 March 2009.
- Noyer, Christian (12 January 2016). "Thoughts on the zero lower bound in relation with monetary and financial stability". Bank for International Settlements. Retrieved 18 January 2016. Cite journal requires
|journal=
(help) - Mishkin, Frederic S. (2000). "Inflation Targeting in Emerging-Market Countries" (PDF). American Economic Review. 90 (2): 105–109. doi:10.1257/aer.90.2.105.
- See the Czech National Bank's website
- N. Nergiz Dincer and Barry Eichengreen (2014): "Central Bank Transparency and Independence: Updates and New Measures", International Journal of Central Banking, March 2014, pp. 189-253.
- Ali Alichi, Jaromir Benes, Joshua Felman, Irene Feng, Charles Freedman, Douglas Laxton, Evan Tanner, David Vavra, and Hou Wang (2015): "Frontiers of Monetary Policymaking: Adding the Exchange Rate as a Tool to Combat Deflationary Risks in the Czech Republic", International Monetary Fund, Working Paper No. 15/74.
- Michal Franta, Tomas Holub, Petr Kral, Ivana Kubicova, Katerina Smidkova, Borek Vasicek (2014): "The Exchange Rate as an Instrument at Zero Interest Rates: The Case of the Czech Republic", Czech National Bank, Research and Policy Note No. 3/2014.
- Skorepa, M., and Hampl, M. (2014): "Evolution of the Czech National Bank’s holdings of foreign exchange reserves", BIS Papers No. 78, pp. 159-169.
- "Why does the Federal Reserve aim for 2 percent inflation over time?". The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Retrieved 8 March 2015.
- As quoted on page 158 of Poole, W. (2006), "Inflation targeting", speech delivered to Junior Achievement of Arkansas, Inc., Little Rock, Arkansas, 16 February 2006. Published in Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, vol. 88, no. 3 (May–June 2006), pp. 155-164.
- Fraher, John (5 June 2008). "King May Be More Irritant Than Ally for Brown at BOE". Bloomberg Exclusive. Retrieved 5 August 2008.
- Bernanke, Ben S. (25 March 2003). A Perspective on Inflation Targeting. Annual Washington Policy Conference of the National Association of Business Economists. Washington, D.C.
- Ben S. Bernanke and Frederic S. Mishkin, (1997), "Inflation targeting: a new framework for monetary policy?", The Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 11, no. 2 (Spring 1997), pp. 97-116.
- Muth, John F. (1961). "Rational Expectations and the Theory of Price Movements". Econometrica. 29 (3): 315–335. doi:10.2307/1909635. JSTOR 1909635.
- Galbács, Peter (2015). "The Rational Expectations Hypothesis as a Key Element of New Classical Macroeconomics". The Theory of New Classical Macroeconomics. A Positive Critique. Contributions to Economics. Heidelberg/New York/Dordrecht/London: Springer. pp. 53–90. doi:10.1007/978-3-319-17578-2. ISBN 978-3-319-17578-2.
- Bernank, Ben S.; Laubach, Thomas; Mishkin, Frederic S.; Posen, Adam S. (2001). Inflation targeting: lessons from the international experience. Princeton Univ. Press. ISBN 9780691086897.
- John C. Williams , President and CEO , Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco (31 October 2014). "Inflation Targeting and the Global Financial Crisis: Successes and Challenges". Federal Reserve Board of San Francisco. Retrieved 1 December 2016.CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
- Maurice Obstfeld (2014). "Never Say Never: Commentary on a Policymaker's Reflections" (PDF). IMF Economic Review. 62 (4): 656–693. doi:10.1057/imfer.2014.12.
- "Inflation Report". Bank of England. Retrieved 20 January 2016.
- Janet L. Yellen (24 February 2015). Monetary Policy Report (PDF). Washington, D.C.: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
- Amira, Beldi; Mouldi, Djelassi; Feridun, Mete (2012). "Growth effects of inflation targeting revisited: empirical evidence from emerging markets". Applied Economics Letters. 20 (6): 587–591. doi:10.1080/13504851.2012.718054.
- Benchimol, Jonathan; Fourçans, André (2019). "Central bank losses and monetary policy rules: a DSGE investigation". International Review of Economics & Finance. 61 (1): 289–303. doi:10.1016/j.iref.2019.01.010.
- Quiggin, John (26 January 2012). "Inflation target tyranny". Retrieved 28 January 2012.
- Svensson, Lars (21 September 2009). "Flexible inflation targeting – lessons from the financial crisis" (PDF). speech at the workshop "Towards a new framework for monetary policy? Lessons from the crisis", organized by the Netherlands Bank, Amsterdam.
- "BoJ to pursue inflation target 'flexibly'". Financial Times. 11 April 2013. Retrieved 20 January 2016.
- Frankel, Jeffrey (16 May 2012). "The Death of Inflation Targeting". Project Syndicate.
- Lucrezia Reichlin and Richard Baldwin, eds. (2013), "Is Inflation Targeting Dead? Central Banking After the Crisis", Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR)
- Haizhou Huang; Shang-Jin Wei (September 2006). "Monetary Policies for Developing Countries: The Role of Institutional Quality". Journal of International Economics. 70: 239–52. doi:10.1016/j.jinteco.2005.09.001.
- John C. Williams, (2014), "Inflation Targeting and the Global Financial Crisis: Successes and Challenges", Essay presentation to the South African Reserve Bank Conference on Fourteen Years of Inflation Targeting in South Africa and the Challenge of a Changing Mandate, Pretoria, South Africa
- Herbener, Jeffrey. "Written Testimony before the Subcommittee on Domestic Monetary Policy and Technology" (PDF). U.S. House of Representatives Financial Services Committee. Retrieved 22 October 2016.
- "Should We Fear Deflation?". Retrieved 22 October 2016.
- Atkeson, Andrew; Kehoe, Patrick J. (2004). "Deflation and Depression: Is There an Empirical Link?" (PDF). American Economic Review. 94 (2): 99–103. doi:10.1257/0002828041301588.
- Jahan, Sarwat (28 March 2012). "Inflation Targeting: Holding the Line". IMF. Retrieved 18 January 2016.
- Roger, Scott (March 2010). "Inflation Targeting Turns 20". Finance & Development. 47 (1). Retrieved 18 January 2016.
- "Speech: Talk by Governor". 4 August 1993.
- Leiderman, Leonardo (1 May 2000). "Monetary Policy Rules and Transmission Mechanisms Under Inflation Targeting in Israel" (PDF). Documentos de Trabajo (Banco Central de Chile). Retrieved 18 October 2009.
- Singer, M. (2015): "From a Peg to Inflation Targeting: CNB Experience", presentation at the High-level Seminar on the Benefits of Adopting a Structured Approach to Policy Analysis, Rabat, Morocco, 21 May 2015
- Galindo, Luis Miguel (13 May 2005). "Alternatives to inflation targeting in Mexico" (PDF) (Amherst/CEDES Conference on Inflation targeting, Buenos Aires). Retrieved October 2009. Check date values in:
|accessdate=
(help) - Marit Tronier Halvorsen (26 September 2013). "Norges Bank holder fast ved inflasjonsmålet". Dagens Næringsliv (in Norwegian).
- "Forsiden". 2 February 2019.
- https://www.cb.is/monetary-policy/inflation-target/
- Rocel C. Felix (2 January 2002). "BSP adopts inflation targeting starting this year". The Philippine Star.
- "National Bank of Georgia". www.nbg.gov.ge. Retrieved 3 January 2018.
- "In historic shift, Fed sets inflation target". Reuters. 26 January 2012. Retrieved 18 January 2016.
- "Doubt Greets Bank of Japan's Easing Shift". The Wall Street Journal. 22 January 2013. Retrieved 18 January 2016.
- https://cbr.ru/eng/publ/ddcp/2014_01_ddcp_e.pdf
- http://nationalbank.kz/?docid=3326&switch=english
- https://bank.gov.ua/monetary/about
- https://zakon.rada.gov.ua/laws/show/v0541500-15
- "India adopts inflation target of 4% for next five years under monetary policy framework".
- "Inflation Targeting Regime in Argentina. Press conference".
- "Policy Rules for Open Economies" Archived 17 September 2009 at the Wayback Machine
- "Inflation-Targeting, Flexible Exchange Rates and Macroeconomic Performance since the Great Recession" (PDF). The Centre for European Policy Studies. March 2014. Retrieved 28 December 2014.