Criticism of the Federal Reserve

The Federal Reserve System (also known as "the Fed") has faced various criticisms since it was authorized in 1913.[1] Nobel laureate economist Milton Friedman and his fellow monetarist Anna Schwartz criticized the Fed's response to the Wall Street Crash of 1929 arguing that it greatly exacerbated the Great Depression.[2] More recent prominent critics include former Congressman Ron Paul.[3]

Surveys of economists show overwhelming opposition to abolishing the Federal Reserve or undermining its independence.[4][5] According to Princeton University economist Alan S. Blinder, "mountains of empirical evidence support the proposition that greater central bank independence produces not only less inflation but superior macroeconomic performance, e.g., lower and less volatile inflation with no more volatility in output."[5]

Creation

An early version of the Federal Reserve Act was drafted in 1910 on Jekyll Island, Georgia, by Republican Senator Nelson Aldrich, chairman of the National Monetary Commission, and several Wall Street bankers. The final version, with provisions intended to improve public oversight and weaken the influence of the New York banking establishment, was drafted by Democratic Congressman Carter Glass of Virginia.[6] The structure of the Fed was a compromise between the desire of the bankers for a central bank under their control and the desire of President Woodrow Wilson to create a decentralized structure under public control.[1] The Federal Reserve Act was approved by Congress and signed by President Wilson in December 1913.[1]

Inflation policy

In The Case Against the Fed, Murray Rothbard argued that, although a supposed core function of the Federal Reserve is to maintain a low level of inflation, its policies (like those of other central banks) have actually aggravated inflation. This occurs when the Fed creates too much fiat money backed by nothing. He called the Fed policy of money creation "legalized counterfeiting" and favored a return to the gold standard.[7] He wrote:

[I]t is undeniable that, ever since the Fed was visited upon us in 1914, our inflations have been more intense, and our depressions far deeper, than ever before. There is only one way to eliminate chronic inflation, as well as the booms and busts brought by that system of inflationary credit: and that is to eliminate the counterfeiting that constitutes and creates that inflation. And the only way to do that is to abolish legalized counterfeiting: that is, to abolish the Federal Reserve System, and return to the gold standard, to a monetary system where a market-produced metal, such as gold, serves as the standard money, and not paper tickets printed by the Federal Reserve.[8]

Effectiveness and policies

The Federal Reserve has been criticized as not meeting its goals of greater stability and low inflation.[9] This has led to a number of proposed changes including advocacy of different policy rules[10] or dramatic restructuring of the system itself.[11]

Milton Friedman concluded that while governments do have a role in the monetary system[12] he was critical of the Federal Reserve due to its poor performance and felt it should be abolished.[13][14] Friedman believed that the Federal Reserve System should ultimately be replaced with a computer program.[11] He favored a system that would automatically buy and sell securities in response to changes in the money supply.[15] This proposal has become known as Friedman's k-percent rule.[16]

Others have proposed NGDP targeting as an alternative rule to guide and improve central bank policy.[17][18] Prominent supporters include Scott Sumner,[19] David Beckworth,[20] and Tyler Cowen.[21]

Congress

Several members of Congress have criticized the Fed. Senator Robert Owen, whose name was on the Glass-Owen Federal Reserve Act, believed that the Fed was not performing as promised. He said:

The Federal Reserve Board was created to control, regulate and stabilize credit in the interest of all people. . . . The Federal Reserve Board is the most gigantic financial power in all the world. Instead of using this great power as the Federal Reserve Act intended that it should, the board . . . delegated this power to the banks.[22][23]

Representative Louis T. McFadden, Chairman of the House Committee on Banking and Currency from 1920 to 1931, accused the Federal Reserve of deliberately causing the Great Depression. In several speeches made shortly after he lost the chairmanship of the committee, McFadden claimed that the Federal Reserve was run by Wall Street banks and their affiliated European banking houses. In one 1932 House speech (that has been criticized as bluster[24]), he stated:

Mr. Chairman, we have in this country one of the most corrupt Institutions the world has ever known. I refer to the Federal Reserve Board and the Federal Reserve banks; . . . This evil institution has impoverished and ruined the people of the United States . . . through the corrupt practices of the moneyed vultures who control it.[25]

Many members of Congress who have been involved in the House and Senate Banking and Currency Committees have been open critics of the Federal Reserve, including Chairmen Wright Patman,[26] Henry Reuss,[27] and Henry B. Gonzalez. Representative Ron Paul, Chairman of the Monetary Policy Subcommittee in 2011, is known as a staunch opponent of the Federal Reserve System.[28] He routinely introduced bills to abolish the Federal Reserve System,[29] three of which gained approval in the House but lost in the Senate.[30]

Congressman Paul also introduced H.R. 459: Federal Reserve Transparency Act of 2011,[31][32] This act required an audit of the Federal Reserve Board and the twelve regional banks, with particular attention to the valuation of its securities. His son, Senator Rand Paul, has introduced similar legislation in subsequent sessions of Congress.[33]

Great Depression (1929)

Money supply decreased significantly between Black Tuesday and the Bank Holiday in March 1933 when there were massive bank runs across the United States
Crowd gathering on Wall Street after the 1929 crash.

Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz stated that the Fed pursued an erroneously restrictive monetary policy, exacerbating the Great Depression. After the stock market crash in 1929, the Fed continued its contraction (decrease) of the money supply and refused to save banks that were struggling with bank runs. This mistake, critics charge, allowed what might have been a relatively mild recession to explode into catastrophe. Friedman and Schwartz believed that the depression was "a tragic testimonial to the importance of monetary forces."[34] Before the establishment of the Federal Reserve, the banking system had dealt with periodic crises (such as in the Panic of 1907) by suspending the convertibility of deposits into currency. In 1907, the system nearly collapsed and there was an extraordinary intervention by an ad-hoc coalition assembled by J. P. Morgan. In the years 1910–1913, the bankers demanded a central bank to address this structural weakness. Friedman suggested that a similar intervention should have been followed during the banking panic at the end of 1930. This might have stopped the vicious circle of forced liquidation of assets at depressed prices, just as suspension of convertibility in 1893 and 1907 had quickly ended the liquidity crises at the time.[35]

Essentially, in the monetarist view, the Great Depression was caused by the fall of the money supply. Friedman and Schwartz note that "[f]rom the cyclical peak in August 1929 to a cyclical trough in March 1933, the stock of money fell by over a third."[36] The result was what Friedman calls "The Great Contraction"—a period of falling income, prices, and employment caused by the choking effects of a restricted money supply. The mechanism suggested by Friedman and Schwartz was that people wanted to hold more money than the Federal Reserve was supplying. People thus hoarded money by consuming less. This, in turn, caused a contraction in employment and production, since prices were not flexible enough to immediately fall. Friedman and Schwartz argued the Federal Reserve allowed the money supply to plummet because of ineptitude and poor leadership.[37]

Many have since agreed with this theory, including Ben Bernanke, Chairman of the Federal Reserve from 2006 until 2014, who, in a speech honoring Friedman and Schwartz, said:

Let me end my talk by abusing slightly my status as an official representative of the Federal Reserve. I would like to say to Milton and Anna: Regarding the Great Depression, you're right. We did it. We're very sorry. But thanks to you, we won't do it again.[38][39]

Friedman has said that ideally he would prefer to "abolish the Federal Reserve and replace it with a computer."[40] He preferred a system that would increase the money supply at some fixed rate, and he thought that "leaving monetary and banking arrangements to the market would have produced a more satisfactory outcome than was actually achieved through government involvement".[41]

In contrast to Friedman's argument that the Fed did too little to ease after the crisis, Murray Rothbard argued that the crisis was caused by the Fed being too loose in the 1920s in the book America's Great Depression.

Global financial crisis (2007–08)

Federal Funds Rate compared to U.S. Treasury interest rates

Some economists, such as John B. Taylor,[42] have asserted that the Fed was responsible, at least partially, for the United States housing bubble which occurred prior to the 2007 recession. They claim that the Fed kept interest rates too low following the 2001 recession.[43] The housing bubble then led to the credit crunch. Then-Chairman Alan Greenspan disputes this interpretation. He points out that the Fed's control over the long-term interest rates (to which critics refer) is only indirect. The Fed did raise the short-term interest rate over which it has control (i.e., the federal funds rate), but the long-term interest rate (which usually follows the former) did not increase.[44][45]

The Federal Reserve's role as a supervisor and regulator has been criticized as being ineffective. Former U.S. Senator Chris Dodd, then-chairman of the United States Senate Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, remarked about the Fed's role in the 2007-2008 economic crisis, "We saw over the last number of years when they took on consumer protection responsibilities and the regulation of bank holding companies, it was an abysmal failure."

Republican and Tea Party criticism

During several recent elections, the Tea Party movement has made the Federal Reserve a major point of attack, which has been picked up by Republican candidates across the country. Former Congressman Ron Paul (R) of Texas and his son Senator Rand Paul (R) of Kentucky have long attacked the Fed, arguing that it is hurting the economy by devaluing the dollar. They argue that its monetary policies cause booms and busts when the Fed creates too much or too little fiat money. Ron Paul's book End the Fed repeatedly points out that the Fed engages in money creation "out of thin air."[46] He argued that interest rates should be set by market forces, not by the Federal Reserve.[47] Paul argues that the booms, bubbles and busts of the business cycle are caused by the Federal Reserve's actions.[48]

In the book Paul argues that "the government and its banking cartel have together stolen $0.95 of every dollar as they have pursued a relentlessly inflationary policy." David Andolfatto of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis said the statement was "just plain false" and "stupid" while noting that legitimate arguments can be made against the Federal Reserve.[49] University of Oregon economist Mark Thoma described it as an "absurd" statement which data does not support.[50]

Surveys of economists show overwhelming opposition to abolishing the Federal Reserve or undermining its independence.[4][5] According to Princeton University economist Alan S. Blinder, "mountains of empirical evidence support the proposition that greater central bank independence produces not only less inflation but superior macroeconomic performance, e.g., lower and less volatile inflation with no more volatility in output."[5]

Private ownership or control

According to the Congressional Research Service:

Because the regional Federal Reserve Banks are privately owned, and most of their directors are chosen by their stockholders, it is common to hear assertions that control of the Fed is in the hands of an elite. In particular, it has been rumored that control is in the hands of a very few people holding "class A stock" in the Fed.

As explained, there is no stock in the system, only in each regional Bank. More important, individuals do not own stock in Federal Reserve Banks. The stock is held only by banks who are members of the system. Each bank holds stock proportionate to its capital. Ownership and membership are synonymous. Moreover, there is no such thing as "class A" stock. All stock is the same.

This stock, furthermore, does not carry with it the normal rights and privileges of ownership. Most significantly, member banks, in voting for the directors of the Federal Reserve Banks of which they are a member, do not get voting rights in proportion to the stock they hold. Instead, each member bank regardless of size gets one vote. Concentration of ownership of Federal Reserve Bank stock, therefore, is irrelevant to the issue of control of the system (italics in original).[51]

According to the web site for the Federal Reserve System, the individual Federal Reserve Banks "are the operating arms of the central banking system, and they combine both public and private elements in their makeup and organization."[52] Each bank has a nine-member board of directors: three elected by the commercial banks in the Bank's region, and six chosen – three each by the member banks and the Board of Governors – "to represent the public with due consideration to the interests of agriculture, commerce, industry, services, labor and consumers."[53] These regional banks are in turn controlled by the Federal Reserve Board of Governors, whose members are appointed by the President of the United States.

Member banks ("[a]bout 38 percent of the nation's more than 8,000 banks")[54] are required to own capital stock in their regional banks,[54][55] and the regional banks pay a set 6% dividend on the member banks' paid-in capital stock (not the regional banks' profits) each year, returning the rest to the US Treasury Department.[56] The Fed has noted that this has created "some confusion about 'ownership'":

[Although] the Reserve Banks issue shares of stock to member banks...owning Reserve Bank stock is quite different from owning stock in a private company. The Reserve Banks are not operated for profit, and ownership of a certain amount of stock is, by law, a condition of membership in the System. The stock may not be sold, traded, or pledged as security for a loan….[57]

In his textbook, Monetary Policy and the Financial System, Paul M. Horvitz, the former Director of Research for the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, stated,

...the member banks can exert some rights of ownership by electing some members of the Board of Directors of the Federal Reserve Bank [applicable to those member banks]. For all practical purposes, however, member bank ownership of the Federal Reserve System is merely a fiction. The Federal Reserve Banks are not operated for the purpose of earning profits for their stockholders. The Federal Reserve System does earn a profit in the normal course of its operations, but these profits, above the 6% statutory dividend, do not belong to the member banks. All net earnings after expenses and dividends are paid to the Treasury.[58]

In the American Political Science Review, Michael D. Reagan[59] wrote,

...the "ownership" of the Reserve Banks by the commercial banks is symbolic; they do not exercise the proprietary control associated with the concept of ownership nor share, beyond the statutory dividend, in Reserve Bank "profits." ...Bank ownership and election at the base are therefore devoid of substantive significance, despite the superficial appearance of private bank control that the formal arrangement creates.[60][61]

Transparency issues

One critique is that the Federal Open Market Committee, which is part of the Federal Reserve System, lacks transparency and is not sufficiently audited.[62] A report by Bloomberg News asserts that the majority of Americans believes that the System should be held more accountable or that it should be abolished.[63] Another critique is the contention that the public should have a right to know what goes on in the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) meetings.[64][65][66]

gollark: I would simply simulate a "hurdy-gurdy" if desired.
gollark: Due to PIERB decree, ABR apiotrackers™ are quite low-resolution.
gollark: ?
gollark: Oh, did qh4os cease to exist
gollark: At the end of the timestep.

See also

References

  1. Johnson, Roger T. (February 2010). "Historical Beginnings... The Federal Reserve" (PDF). Federal Reserve Bank of Boston. Retrieved 30 December 2014.
  2. Milton Friedman; Anna Jacobson Schwartz (2008). The Great Contraction, 1929–1933 (New Edition). Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0691137940.
  3. Ron Paul (2009). End the Fed. Grand Central Publishing. ISBN 9780446568180. out of thin air.
  4. "Fed policy". www.igmchicago.org. Retrieved 2019-01-04.
  5. Blinder, Alan (2010). "How Central Should the Central Bank Be?" (PDF). Journal of Economic Literature. 48: 123–133. doi:10.1257/jel.48.1.123.
  6. Wicker, Elmus (2005). The Great Debate On Banking Reform - Nelson Aldrich And The Origins Of The Fed. Ohio State University Press. pp. 4–6. ISBN 9780814210000.
  7. Murray Rothbard (2007). The Case Against the Fed. Ludwig Von Mises Institute. pp. 27–29, 146. ISBN 978-0945466178.
  8. Murray Rothbard (2007). The Case Against the Fed. Ludwig Von Mises Institute. p. 146. ISBN 978-0945466178.
  9. Selgin, George; Lastrapes, William D. (2012). "Has the Fed been a failure?". Journal of Macroeconomics. 34 (3): 569–596. doi:10.1016/j.jmacro.2012.02.003.
  10. Salter, Alexander (2014-11-21). "An Introduction to Monetary Policy Rules". Mercatus Center. Retrieved 2019-03-01.
  11. "Mr. Market". Hoover Institution. January 30, 1999. Archived from the original on September 23, 2018. Retrieved September 22, 2018.
  12. Friedman, Milton; Schwartz, Anna J. (1986). "Has government any role in money?". Journal of Monetary Economics. 17 (1): 37–62. doi:10.1016/0304-3932(86)90005-X.
  13. Milton Friedman – Abolish The Fed Archived June 11, 2015, at the Wayback Machine. Youtube: "I have long been in favor of abolishing it."
  14. "My first preference would be to abolish the Federal Reserve" on YouTube
  15. Friedman, M. (1996). The Counter-Revolution in Monetary Theory. In Explorations in Economic Liberalism (pp. 3-21). Palgrave Macmillan, London. "It is precisely this leeway, this looseness in the relation, this lack of a mechanical one-to-one correspondence between changes in money and in income that is the primary reason why I have long favored for the USA a quasi-automatic monetary policy under which the quantity of money would grow at a steady rate of 4 or 5 per cent per year, month-in, month-out."
  16. Salter, A. W. (2014). An Introduction to Monetary Policy Rules. Mercatus Workıng Paper. George Mason University.
  17. Sheedy, Kevin D. (2014). "Debt and incomplete financial markets: a case for nominal GDP targeting" (PDF). Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. 45 (1): 301–373.
  18. Benchimol, Jonathan; Fourçans, André (2019). "Central bank losses and monetary policy rules: a DSGE investigation". International Review of Economics & Finance. 61 (1): 289–303. doi:10.1016/j.iref.2019.01.010.
  19. Sumner, Scott (2012). "The case for nominal GDP targeting". Mercatus Research. doi:10.2139/ssrn.3255027.
  20. Beckworth, David; Hendrickson, Joshua (2020). "Nominal GDP targeting and the Taylor rule on an even playing field". Journal of Money, Credit and Banking. 52 (1): 269–286. doi:10.1111/jmcb.12602.
  21. Cowen, Tyler (2016-08-23). "Why nominal GDP targeting is an especially good idea right now". Marginal Revolution. Retrieved 2019-03-01.
  22. Mullins, Eustace (2009). The Secrets of the Federal Reserve. Bridger House Publishers. ISBN 978-0-9656492-1-6. Archived from the original on 2005-11-26. Retrieved 2014-12-30.
  23. "Owen criticises reserve board", The New York Times (July 25, 1921)
  24. Flaherty, Edward (6 Sep 2000). "Myth #10. The Legendary Tirade of Louis T. McFadden". Political Research Associates.
  25. McFadden, Louis (June 10, 1932). Congressional Record, June 10, 1932, Louis T. McFadden.
  26. "Banking: Fight over the Federal Reserve". Time. 14 February 1964. Retrieved 20 August 2010.
  27. Uchitelle, Louis (24 August 1989). "Moves On in Congress to Lift Secrecy at the Federal Reserve". The New York Times. Retrieved 20 August 2010.
  28. Ron Paul (2009). End the Fed. Grand Central Publishing. ISBN 9780446568180. The Fed was the cause of the Depression.
  29. E.g., H.R. 2755 (110th Congress); H.R. 2778 (108th Congress); H.R. 5356 (107th Congress); H.R. 1148 (106th Congress)
  30. "H.R. 2755: Federal Reserve Board Abolition Act". GovTrack.us. 15 June 2007.
  31. "H.R. 459: Federal Reserve Transparency Act of 2011". GovTrack.us. 26 January 2011.
  32. Bendery, Jennifer (26 July 2012). "Nancy Pelosi: 'Audit The Fed' Bill Is Likely Going Nowhere". Huffington Post.
  33. Stiles, Megan (December 18, 2015). "Senate Vote on Audit the Fed Scheduled for January 12th". Campaign for Liberty.
  34. Milton Friedman; Anna Jacobson Schwartz (2008). The Great Contraction, 1929–1933 (New Edition). Princeton University Press. pp. xviii, 13. ISBN 978-0691137940.
  35. Milton Friedman; Anna Schwartz (2008). The Great Contraction, 1929–1933 (New Edition). Princeton University Press. p. 28. ISBN 978-0691137940.
  36. Milton Friedman; Anna Schwartz (2008). The Great Contraction, 1929–1933 (New Edition). Princeton University Press. p. 11. ISBN 978-0691137940.
  37. Chang-Tai Hsie; Christina D. Romer (2006). "Was the Federal Reserve Constrained by the Gold Standard During the Great Depression?" (PDF). Journal of Economic History.
  38. Bernanke, Ben S. (8 Nov 2002). "Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke". FederalReserve.gov. Retrieved 1 Jan 2007.
  39. Milton Friedman; Anna Jacobson Schwartz (2008). The Great Contraction, 1929–1933 (New Edition). Princeton University Press. p. 247. ISBN 978-0691137940.
  40. O'Toole, Kathleen (9 September 1997). "Greenspan voices concerns about quality of economic statistics". Stanford News Service.
  41. Ebeling, Richard M. (1 March 1999). "Monetary Central Planning and the State, Part 27: Milton Friedman's Second Thoughts on the Costs of Paper Money". fff.org.
  42. Taylor, John B. (10 January 2010). "The Fed and the Crisis: A Reply to Ben Bernanke". The Wall Street Journal. Retrieved 19 November 2012.
  43. Henderson, David (27 March 2009). "Did the Fed Cause the Housing Bubble?". The Wall Street Journal.
  44. Jim Lehrer (September 18, 2007). Greenspan Examines Federal Reserve, Mortgage Crunch. PBS Newshour. Alan Greenspan. NewsHour Productions LLC.
  45. Labonte, Marc; Makinen, Gail E. (19 March 2008). "Federal Reserve Interest Rate Changes: 2000-2008" (PDF). assets.opencrs.com. Archived from the original (PDF) on 30 December 2014.
  46. Ron Paul (2009). End the Fed. Grand Central Publishing. ISBN 9780446568180. out of thin air.
  47. "A lonely voice against the Fed now leads a chorus". The Washington Post. 2009.
  48. "What Happens If We End the Fed?". U.S. News. 2011.
  49. Andolfatto, David (2011-03-23). "MacroMania: Ron Paul's Money Illusion (Sequel)". MacroMania. Retrieved 2019-01-04.
  50. "Economist's View: Ron Paul's Money Illusion: The Sequel". economistsview.typepad.com. Retrieved 2019-01-04.
  51. Woodward, G. Thomas (31 July 1996). "Money and the Federal Reserve System: Myth and Reality". Report No. 96–672 E. Congressional Research Service, Library of Congress. OCLC 39127005.
  52. The Federal Reserve System: Purposes and Functions (PDF) (9th ed.). Federal Reserve. June 2005. Retrieved 30 December 2014.
  53. "What We Do". New York Fed. March 2010. Retrieved 30 December 2014.
  54. "Federal Reserve Bank Ownership". Factcheck.org. 31 March 2008. Retrieved 30 December 2014.
  55. "12 U.S.C. § 282 et seq". Cornell University Law School.
  56. "12 U.S.C. § 289(a)(1)(A)". Cornell University Law School.
  57. "Who owns the Federal Reserve?". Federal Reserve. Retrieved 30 December 2014.
  58. Horvitz, Paul M. (1974). Monetary Policy and the Financial System (3rd ed.). Prentice Hall. p. 293. ISBN 9780135998861.
  59. Not to be confused with Michael Edward Reagan, the son of President Ronald Reagan.
  60. Reagan, Michael D. (March 1961). "The Political Structure of the Federal Reserve System". American Political Science Review. 55 (1): 64–76. doi:10.2307/1976050. JSTOR 1976050.
  61. Mittra, S. (1970). Money and Banking: Theory, Analysis, and Policy. New York: Random House. p. 153.
  62. Poole, William (July 2002). "Untold story of FOMC: Secrecy is exaggerated". St. Louis Federal Reserve.
  63. Zumbrun, Joshua (9 December 2010). "Majority of Americans Say Fed Should Be Reined In or Abolished, Poll Shows". Bloomberg.
  64. Poole, William (6 October 2004). "FOMC Transparency" (PDF). Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. 87: 1–9.
  65. "Remarks by Chairman Alan Greenspan - Transparency in monetary policy". Federal Reserve. 11 October 2001.
  66. "Remarks by Vice Chairman Roger W. Ferguson, Jr.—Transparency in Central Banking: Rationale and Recent Developments". Federal Reserve. 19 April 2001.
This article is issued from Wikipedia. The text is licensed under Creative Commons - Attribution - Sharealike. Additional terms may apply for the media files.