Just price
The just price is a concept that involves both economics and ethics. The idea attempts to distinguish between fair and unfair methods of gain in commerce.
“”To sell a thing for more than its worth, or to buy it for less than its worth, is in itself unjust and unlawful. |
—Thomas Aquinas |
The dismal science Economics |
Economic Systems |
$ Market Economy |
Major Concepts |
People |
v - t - e |
It was given its classic exposition by the Catholic theologian Thomas Aquinas, though it was not original to him. It flows from the traditional Christian opposition to usury, which originally meant any and all interest on money lent.
The concept of just price in its traditional sense is largely considered obsolete. For example, the tradition of artisan's guilds deciding the prices of the goods would today be considered a cartel, an unethical and often illegal practice. That is not to mean that in certain situations too high or too low prices could not become a problem, but the issue is seen to lie in the imperfect competition, or possibly the exploitation of an insufficiently informed party, not in the deviation of prices from a specific range per se.
A sort of fraud
Aristotle, one of Aquinas's chief sources, is another source for Aquinas's ethical stance against usury. Aristotle held that there was something 'unnatural' about money begetting money, suggesting that Aristotle at least anticipated the fact that interest-based financial systems introduce a multiplier effect into the money supply, resulting in abstract sums of money in ledgers that exceed the amount of available specie. What makes usury 'unnatural' is that it automatically results in the existence of an aggregate debt larger than the amount of currency available to pay it. For Aristotle, such an economy would be inherently unstable and unsustainable. Apparently it never occurred to these folks that one is essentially renting money to someone, and that getting someone money at a time when they need it might be adding a type of value.
But, of course, Aquinas's position begins with the Bible. The fact that God condemned usury unequivocally in both the Old and New Testaments constrained Aquinas's result, of course. But to these concerns, Aquinas added an additional argument, based on the Golden Rule. The Christian should "do unto others as you would have them do unto you", meaning he should trade value for value. Aquinas was not against all profit from trade, but held instead that it was immoral to take a profit without having added value. Aquinas therefore argued that it was actively immoral, and a sort of fraud[1], for a seller to raise prices in the wake of a disaster creating a local shortage:[1][note 1]
“”If someone would be greatly helped by something belonging to someone else, and the seller not similarly harmed by losing it, the seller must not sell for a higher price: because the usefulness that goes to the buyer comes not from the seller, but from the buyer's needy condition: no one ought to sell something that doesn't belong to him. |
—Summa Theologiæ, 2-2, q. 77, art. 1 |
Aquinas's reasoning here prefigures to some extent the labor theory of value
Just price in different societies
The concept of a just price tends to arise spontaneously in traditional rural and agricultural societies, and recurs with minor variations in many places. It arises in places where each person and each household is a consumer as well as a producer. Social networks create mutual understandings to promote the survival of these social units in the face of scarcity. These social ties operate to prevent the economic actors in traditional societies from behaving to maximize personal profit.
In these places, traditional understandings arise as to the relative value of various goods and services. Prices are not independently renegotiated for each transaction in an impersonal, anonymous market. Traditional staple foods and other goods deemed necessary for the survival of the community acquire customary prices; dearth or plenty should be shared by all. These traditional understandings acquire the force of custom, and with increased social complexity may eventually acquire the force of law.[2]
Even in developed industrial societies, people continue to identify staple goods deemed necessary for the continuing existence of the society, such as gasoline and electricity; and often attempt to regulate the prices of such goods to prevent them from being set entirely by the operations of supply, demand, and limited human knowledge. Upticks in the prices of these goods generate general resentment. While it makes economic sense for prices to rise significantly due to a shortage, people consider this to be foul play, and would punish businesses that do so. This is why price gouging of common products are rare.[3]
Backpedaling
Like the traditional Christian understanding of usury, the concept of the just price has been subject to a great deal of backpedaling. The School of Salamancaexcuses justifications for rape, murder, and theft in the Book of Exodus.
They imagined that everyone had the right to travel everywhere for purposes of trade; since the more organized Natives sought to prevent them from going wherever they want, this made the conquest of the Americas a just war; and besides, they were just pagans. Martín de Azpilcueta
None of these teachings were made with the intention of entirely overthrowing the Thomist moral analysis, but they soon became the exceptions that swallowed the rule. Whether Aquinas or the Salamancans have the better part of this argument is something you must decide for yourself. On the other hand, a rhetorical tradition beginning with Joseph Schumpeter's History of Economic Analysis (1954) has tended to belittle the Thomist position and promote the Salamancans as a progressive force moving towards modernity. According to Laurence M. Vance, "[t]he mention of just price theory either invokes a blank stare, or, in the case of those familiar with the term, the dismissal of the notion as a discredited medieval religious doctrine."[5]
Aquinas's position may be untenable, or simply too radical to implement in current societies, but it is not obvious nonsense. Murray Rothbard has identified the Salamancans as precursors of the Austrian school of economics,[citation needed] which ought to tell you something.
External links
- Thomas Aquinas, Summa Theologiæ: Whether it is lawful to sell a thing for more than its worth?
- Blaise Pascal, "On Usury", from Lettres provinciales.
- Lawrence M. Vance, The myth of the just price. Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2008.
See also
Notes
- Si vero aliquis multum iuvetur ex re alterius quam accepit, ille vero qui vendidit non damnificatur carendo re illa, non debet eam supervendere. Quia utilitas quae alteri accrescit non est ex vendente, sed ex conditione ementis, nullus autem debet vendere alteri quod non est suum. . .
References
- Thomas Aquinas, Summa Theologica, 2ª-2ae q. 77 pr.: Deinde considerandum est de peccatis quae sunt circa voluntarias commutationes. Et primo, de fraudulentia quae committitur in emptionibus et venditionibus ...
- James C. Scott: The Moral Economy of the Peasant: Rebellion and Subsistence in Southeast Asia. (Yale, 1977). ISBN 0-300-02190-9
- Jacob Goldstein, Why Economists Love Price Gouging, And Why It's So Rare, NPR, 2012.
- Blaise Pascal, Lettres provinciales, letter 8.
- The Myth of the Just Price